Monetary Policy for all? Inequality and the Conduct of Monetary Policy | The Business Standard
Skip to main content
  • Latest
  • Economy
    • Banking
    • Stocks
    • Industry
    • Analysis
    • Bazaar
    • RMG
    • Corporates
    • Aviation
  • Videos
    • TBS Today
    • TBS Stories
    • TBS World
    • News of the day
    • TBS Programs
    • Podcast
    • Editor's Pick
  • World+Biz
  • Features
    • Panorama
    • The Big Picture
    • Pursuit
    • Habitat
    • Thoughts
    • Splash
    • Mode
    • Tech
    • Explorer
    • Brands
    • In Focus
    • Book Review
    • Earth
    • Food
    • Luxury
    • Wheels
  • Subscribe
    • Epaper
    • GOVT. Ad
  • More
    • Sports
    • TBS Graduates
    • Bangladesh
    • Supplement
    • Infograph
    • Archive
    • Gallery
    • Long Read
    • Interviews
    • Offbeat
    • Magazine
    • Climate Change
    • Health
    • Cartoons
  • বাংলা
The Business Standard

Tuesday
July 08, 2025

Sign In
Subscribe
  • Latest
  • Economy
    • Banking
    • Stocks
    • Industry
    • Analysis
    • Bazaar
    • RMG
    • Corporates
    • Aviation
  • Videos
    • TBS Today
    • TBS Stories
    • TBS World
    • News of the day
    • TBS Programs
    • Podcast
    • Editor's Pick
  • World+Biz
  • Features
    • Panorama
    • The Big Picture
    • Pursuit
    • Habitat
    • Thoughts
    • Splash
    • Mode
    • Tech
    • Explorer
    • Brands
    • In Focus
    • Book Review
    • Earth
    • Food
    • Luxury
    • Wheels
  • Subscribe
    • Epaper
    • GOVT. Ad
  • More
    • Sports
    • TBS Graduates
    • Bangladesh
    • Supplement
    • Infograph
    • Archive
    • Gallery
    • Long Read
    • Interviews
    • Offbeat
    • Magazine
    • Climate Change
    • Health
    • Cartoons
  • বাংলা
TUESDAY, JULY 08, 2025
Monetary Policy for all? Inequality and the Conduct of Monetary Policy

Global Economy

Niels-Jakob Hansen, Alessandro Lin and Rui C. Mano
30 September, 2020, 08:45 pm
Last modified: 30 September, 2020, 09:19 pm

Related News

  • Can offshore financial centres be a viable monetary policy tool?
  • Bangladesh Bank may seek to delay IMF’s default loan policy
  • Policy tools alone cannot control inflation
  • Bangladesh's Monetary Policy for H2 2025: Controlling inflation and strengthening banking sector
  • Can a contractionary monetary policy cause issues in the long run?

Monetary Policy for all? Inequality and the Conduct of Monetary Policy

Fiscal policies and structural reforms are long known to be powerful mitigators of inequality

Niels-Jakob Hansen, Alessandro Lin and Rui C. Mano
30 September, 2020, 08:45 pm
Last modified: 30 September, 2020, 09:19 pm
Monetary Policy for all? Inequality and the Conduct of Monetary Policy

Inequality in both advanced economies and emerging markets has been on the rise in recent decades. The Covid-19 pandemic has exacerbated and raised awareness of disparities between the rich and poor.

Fiscal policies and structural reforms are long known to be powerful mitigators of inequality. But what role can the central bank play?

In new IMF staff research, we find a case for central bankers to take inequality specifically into account when conducting monetary policy.

The Business Standard Google News Keep updated, follow The Business Standard's Google news channel

A new view on monetary policy

Even though inequality remains outside central banks' mandates, major central bankers are increasingly discussing distributional issues. At the same time, recent advances in economic theory shed new light on the interplay of monetary policy and inequality.

It is now accepted within academia and major central banks that wealth and income inequality affect the effectiveness of monetary policy. This is because the poor, who tend to be more liquidity constrained than the rich, increase their consumption more as their incomes rise in response to an interest rate cut. The same rate cut thus stimulates aggregate consumption more in an economy with a larger proportion of the poor. Relatedly, there is evidence supporting that monetary policy itself can affect inequality.

Our research asks whether inequality affects the way monetary policy should be conducted in a stylized economy where business cycles are driven by innovations in technology. In this setting, a rich person—call her R—owns all the capital. R's income is thus composed of after-tax dividends and wages. In contrast, a poor person—call her P—receives only wages and a transfer from the government financed by the dividend tax. In the model, profits and capital income rise in response to positive productivity shocks, thereby exacerbating inequality. Moreover, wages are tech-biased: when productivity rises, R's share of total wage income goes up, while P's declines. These mechanisms are consistent with U.S. micro- and macro-economic data and match the empirical effects of technology shocks on consumption inequality.

We study implications for monetary policy in two settings. In the first, the central bank chooses the best possible path of interest rates with full information and caring equally about all individuals. This setting is called "optimal policy." In the second setting, the central bank sets monetary policy according to a so-called Taylor rule, which prescribes a given interest rate based on whether inflation and output deviate from desired levels. This second setting is useful because it is closer to what central banks do in practice. In our study, the relevant concept of inequality is the difference in consumption between rich and poor.

Implications for monetary policy

In the first setting, we find that a central bank should place some weight on observed consumption inequality. That means the central bank will use monetary policy, that is, setting interest rates to stimulate growth and wages, which has the effect of reducing consumption inequality while tolerating inflation moving above its target. However, we find that this weight is generally small and thus output and inflation are not that different from those that would prevail if the central bank ignored inequality. Interestingly, a central bank pursuing such "optimal policy" cares progressively less about inflation and more about growth the higher the initial level of inequality. This is because when initial inequality is high the central bank will try harder to adjust interest rates to stabilize wages and protect the consumption of the poor. Thus, stabilizing wages, and hence inequality, coincides with stabilizing growth.

In the second setting, we find that a central bank should pursue an augmented "Taylor rule" targeting also consumption inequality. That means following a positive productivity shock, interest rates should be set lower than the level implied by a standard Taylor rule that targets output and inflation alone. A policy of lower interest rates leads to higher wages which benefits the poor. Beyond lowering inequality, such a policy is also beneficial more generally because it improves inflation and growth outcomes by avoiding excessive tightening of the interest rate in response to a positive productivity shock.

These results suggest that welfare could be improved if central banks take inequality into account when conducting monetary policy, particularly if following typical interest rate rules. Our results of course are model specific and can be complemented by considering additional features, for example, by including differentiated types of labor and hence differentiated wages, or a richer set of available assets. The results bolster the case for more theoretical and empirical work on the issue.


Niels-Jakob Hansen is an economist in the World Economic Studies Division of the IMF's Research Department.

Alessandro Lin a PhD candidate in The Department of Economics at Brown University.

Rui C. Mano is a senior economist in the IMF's Strategy, Policy and Review Department.


Disclaimer: This article first appeared on IMF Blog, and is published by special syndication arrangement.

Top News / World+Biz

Monetary Policy / inequality

Comments

While most comments will be posted if they are on-topic and not abusive, moderation decisions are subjective. Published comments are readers’ own views and The Business Standard does not endorse any of the readers’ comments.

Top Stories

  • Representational image. Photo: TBS
    35% US tariff to be disastrous for Bangladesh's exports, say economists and exporters
  • File Photo: Rajib Dhar/TBS
    Bangladesh faces economic impact as US introduces 35% tariff on exports
  • US President Donald Trump points a finger as he departs for Canada to attend the G7 Leaders' Summit, from Joint Base Andrews in Maryland, US, June 15, 2025. Photo: REUTERS/Kevin Lamarque
    Trump sends letter to Yunus imposing 35% tariff on Bangladeshi products

MOST VIEWED

  • The Mitsubishi Xpander is built with families in mind, ready to handle the daily carpool, grocery runs, weekend getaways, and everything in between. PHOTO: Akif Hamid
    Now made-in-Bangladesh: 2025 Mitsubishi Xpander
  • Illustration: Ashrafun Naher Ananna/TBS Creative
    World’s largest container shipping companies
  • Representational image
    Dhaka gets relief as Trump pushes tariff deadline to 1 Aug
  • A quieter scene at Dhaka University’s central library on 29 June, with seats still unfilled—unlike earlier this year, when the space was overwhelmed by crowds of job aspirants preparing for competitive exams. Photo: Tahmidul Alam Jaeef
    No more long queues at DU Central Library. What changed?
  • Illustration: Duniya Jahan/TBS Creative
    Inflation drops below 9% after 27 months
  • Illustration: Duniya Jahan/TBS Creative
    Young population believe BNP to get 39% of votes, Jamaat 21%, NCP 16% in national polls: Sanem survey

Related News

  • Can offshore financial centres be a viable monetary policy tool?
  • Bangladesh Bank may seek to delay IMF’s default loan policy
  • Policy tools alone cannot control inflation
  • Bangladesh's Monetary Policy for H2 2025: Controlling inflation and strengthening banking sector
  • Can a contractionary monetary policy cause issues in the long run?

Features

Thousands gather to form Bangla Blockade in mass show of support. Photo: TBS

Rebranding rebellion: Why ‘Bangla Blockade’ struck a chord

16h | Panorama
The Mitsubishi Xpander is built with families in mind, ready to handle the daily carpool, grocery runs, weekend getaways, and everything in between. PHOTO: Akif Hamid

Now made-in-Bangladesh: 2025 Mitsubishi Xpander

1d | Wheels
Students of different institutions protest demanding the reinstatement of the 2018 circular cancelling quotas in recruitment in government jobs. Photo: Mehedi Hasan

5 July 2024: Students announce class boycott amid growing protests

3d | Panorama
Contrary to long-held assumptions, Gen Z isn’t politically clueless — they understand both local and global politics well. Photo: TBS

A misreading of Gen Z’s ‘political disconnect’ set the stage for Hasina’s ouster

3d | Panorama

More Videos from TBS

Trump imposes 35% tariff on Bangladeshi products

Trump imposes 35% tariff on Bangladeshi products

1h | TBS World
Much of Iran’s Military Capacities Still Unutilized, General Warns Israel

Much of Iran’s Military Capacities Still Unutilized, General Warns Israel

14h | TBS World
How Trump's tariff chaos could reshape Asia's businesses

How Trump's tariff chaos could reshape Asia's businesses

4h | Others
How will Europe stop Russia's Shadow Fleet?

How will Europe stop Russia's Shadow Fleet?

14h | Others
EMAIL US
contact@tbsnews.net
FOLLOW US
WHATSAPP
+880 1847416158
The Business Standard
  • About Us
  • Contact us
  • Sitemap
  • Advertisement
  • Privacy Policy
  • Comment Policy
Copyright © 2025
The Business Standard All rights reserved
Technical Partner: RSI Lab

Contact Us

The Business Standard

Main Office -4/A, Eskaton Garden, Dhaka- 1000

Phone: +8801847 416158 - 59

Send Opinion articles to - oped.tbs@gmail.com

For advertisement- sales@tbsnews.net